Sunday, March 31, 2013

Current Economic Conditions - SFC Perspective


Real output flows of the US are below potential as evidenced in the low labor participation rate, high unemployment rate and low factory utilization rate (i.e. we’re not using or maintaining a portion of our real asset stocks, Chart 1a, 1b & 1c). This “output gap” is the most urgent economic issue facing the country because this “gap” lowers the country’s standard of living irreversibly (smaller “pie” to go around either now or in the future) and because it has large impacts on the distribution of real/money flows (e.g. newly unemployed get smaller real flows, etc.). The main macro driver of the output gap can be identified by looking at aggregate money flows since these money flows drive real flows. As discussed previously nominal economic growth only occurs via spending of prior period savings or via increases in debt (which creates money stocks that increase money flow/real flow transactions unless used exclusively for existing asset purchases). This is the case because either action by an actor in the economic flow (see previous blog post) increases the money flow rate around the cycle. One way to evaluate these actions is to examine the sectoral balances, which combine these two actions into an overall net saving or net borrowing position by sector (with the net position being zero overall, because again - the US$ economy is "closed" in that there are two sides to every transaction, so every debtor has a creditor). Looking at the sectoral balance graphic (Chart 2) we can see that the foreign sector has not changed much – it is still in surplus (spending less than it earned during the period – subtracting from the economic flow), that the government sector has increased its deficit (but is otherwise similar in sign to prior years) and that the household/business sector has had a drastic swing from deficit (spending more than they are earning) to surplus (spending less than they are earning). Clearly the sector which has had the biggest change is the private domestic sector (households & businesses) and which therefore should be the chief suspect as the main driver for the current malaise.

GDP = Income = C + I + G + (X - M) = Spending = C + S + T

Rearranged:

(I - S) + (G - T) + (X - M) = 0

Chart 1a








Chart 1b


Chart 1c

 
Chart 2



The unusually large surplus in the private domestic sector (households and businesses) is why this recession has been called “a balance sheet recession” since the surplus has been thought to reflect individuals and businesses spending less than their incomes in an effort to “fix” their balance sheets. Savings are being used to either 1) pay off debt (e.g. underwater mortgages, excessive leverage relative to newly adjusted risk assessments (credit market freeze impact, etc.) or 2) increase stocks of money (e.g. increased savings for retirement since housing wealth decreased, increased rainy day fund due to increased perception of financial liquidity risks, etc.). The degree to which each of these factors are driving saving desires is observable in economic data – for example the drop in mortgage debt since the financial crisis (Chart 3) shows that some savings are being used to pay down debt (I’m assuming bank loan write-downs cannot explain the entire decrease since I don’t believe they have the capital to absorb this). More broadly, Chart 4 shows that private debt levels overall have decreased over the last few years, and therefore that increases in saving desires are not all due to increases in money stock hoarding.

Chart 3 


Chart 4


The fact that the private domestic sector is spending less than its income (net) is also of course a function of investment decisions (new debt acquisition) by households and firms, a function which is driven in large part by current capacity utilization (do I currently need the investment?), expectations of future sales/income (will I be able to pay the debt back?) and debt capacity (can I convince banks I’ll pay it back). The previous charts show that saving desires currently exceed desires to borrow by this sector (since the net is a decrease in debt) and that this net balance is unusual, as this sector is usually increasing its stock of real assets via net debt acquisition, which as I have described previously is a good, sustainable process as long as the real assets produced provide the flows that allow the debt to be repaid. Chart 5 and Chart 6 below clearly illustrate that investments by firms (non-residential investment) and investment by households (residential investment) both decreased drastically during the great recession, but that they have both since rebounded. However, while businesses are approaching the level of fixed investment attained during the prior period boom, households are still investing at a much slower pace than before. This data suggests that the continued decrease in money flows (which is producing the output gap) is primarily the result of increased saving desires of businesses and individuals (to pay off debt or to increase money stocks) and decreased housing investment desires of households.

Chart 5


Chart 6



This reality of private sector deleveraging does not necessarily mean that an output gap must occur. The other players in the economic cycle can more than offset this reduction in money flows and in fact lower the output gap relative to pre-crisis levels. The foreign sector can provide money flow increases by spending more USD$ than they earn, yet unfortunately we see, via the sectoral balance diagram, that this is not the case. The foreign sector continues to spend less than they earn (i.e. they have a trade surplus with the US – instead of goods they get USD$ money stocks), which has been a drag on money flows for a few decades now. The drivers for this accumulation of USD$ money stocks are many but include 1) foreign currency reserve needs (to “guarantee” access to foreign goods and to provide foreign currency which can be used to manipulate exchange rates in the future), 2) the result of prior foreign currency interventions made to support export led economic growth strategies and 3) the desirability of USD$ savings vs. foreign currency savings. The foreign sector money flow “leakage” is clearly something the US needs to address as it exacerbates, not helps, the money flow problems coming from private sector saving desires.

With the foreign sector unable to offset the money flow decrease caused by private sector deleveraging the government has been forced to try and fill the gap. Specifically, with the “river” of money around the economic cycle being diverted to the private domestic sector and foreign sector money stocks (lakes) the government has been forced to inject money flows into the economic cycle to maintain real flow production. Since state and local governments are unable to run large, sustained budget deficits (by law) it is the federal government that has been forced to inject money flows. The federal government has been “forced” to act in such a way due to public opinion (e.g. the stimulus act) and, more importantly, due to existing legislation. Such legislation falls under the label of “automatic stabilizers” since they remove money flows when the economic cycle flows are “too large” and add money flows when cycle flows are "too small". We all know of the money injections that increase when the economic cycle slows – unemployment compensation, welfare, food stamps, etc., yet often forget that money flow removal (i.e. taxes) is designed to slow during downturns as well due to the income based source of most federal government imposed taxes. The end result of both the discretionary and “automatic” federal government money flow changes can be seen in Chart 7 – very large money injections which, by accounting identity, produce corresponding debt stocks.

Chart 7



In addition to fiscal policy the government has also responded to the great recession using monetary policy, which is executed thru the Federal Reserve. Most of the Federal Reserve’s post-financial crisis activities (e.g. lowering the Fed Fund’s rate, buying Treasury bonds and private mortgage backed securities) have focused on lowering interest rates in order to 1) make debt levels more manageable (decreasing debt repayment and freeing up money flows for non-interest related purposes), 2) to increase asset prices due to lower discount rates/opportunity costs of capital (which affect money flows via the “wealth effect” ( increased balance sheet net worth)), 3) to encourage new debt accumulation (which may increase money flows) and 4) to decrease saving desires directly thru consumer intertemporal optimization effects. The impact of this monetary policy endeavor is hard to quantify since it works thru multiple pathways and empirical studies have many confounding factors to deal with, but in my opinion the positive effects of these monetary policy actions are vastly over-rated. It is true that lower interest rates have lowered debt service costs (see Chart 8) and increased asset values (see Chart 9), yet I do not believe that lower interest rates appreciably impact intertemporal optimization (see Chart 9a - people do not consume more simply because the real rate of interest has decreased) or business investment (since there are much bigger drivers, like sales, plus the fact that business investment spending is no longer usually funded by new debt (retained earnings provides most funding)). Further, as I repeat often, interest payment transactions impact at least two parties – if debtors pay less interest then creditors receive less interest. The net impact on money flows going to real flow production depends on which party is more likely to spend the resulting money stock on real flows. You might believe that debtors, by their very nature, would be more likely to spend the "saved" interest money flows, except when you realize that the largest debtor is the US government which is not constrained in its spending like non-currency issuing entities are (ignoring the extremely misguided debt limit). The Federal Reserve returned nearly $89 billion to the Treasury in 2012 (see Chart 10) a large part of which is due to interest paid on government bonds that are now owned by the Fed (reserves at the Fed yield much less than the bonds they replace). These interest expense savings reduced the federal budget deficit and the money flow injections they represent. Overall I believe the Fed’s actions since the financial crisis has helped to increase money flow/real flow transactions, but to a small degree and in a way that may not be beneficial in the long term (more on this later).
Chart 8


Chart 9


Chart 9a


Chart 10


The final actor in the economic cycle – the banks, were initially the main cause of the money flow decreases that created the US economic output gap (i.e. when solvency issues became apparent trust between transacting parties disappeared which resulted in a credit freeze - another paper in itself). Due to rule changes and central bank interventions this source of money flow reduction was quickly addressed, and to a large degree the banking system is now operating in a similar manner as before the crisis (sadly). An example of this is shown in Chart 11 – consumer credit (loans to households excluding housing-backed loans) continues to increase (hopefully creating/sustaining human, physical or technological real assets which will allow for debt repayment). [Note that this does not contradict earlier charts – the increase in this type of debt is simply smaller than the decrease in housing debt]. The banking sector is an integral part of the economic cycle but one which is supposed to facilitate, not drive, money flows around the economic cycle. This is of course only partly true, and there are many very important (and troubling) issues surrounding banks, but for the sake of brevity I will not discuss banking in detail at this point but instead focus on bank controlled factors that are contributing to or ameliorating the current output gap.

If you have made it through my last few blog posts you understand that bank lending is constrained by bank capital (shareholder equity) – so the first question must be – is this constraint currently binding? [Note – if you still don’t believe this read the following: http://rwer.wordpress.com/2012/01/26/central-bankers-were-all-post-keynesians-now/ ] Based on government stress tests almost all banks are adequately capitalized and able to issue new loans. This is partly due to continued bank profitability and optimistically valued (or hidden) assets (i.e. asset held off balance sheet or valued based on book value, not market values, due to the partial removal of mark-to-market rules). Lower interest rates (which are set by the Federal Reserve exogenously) impacts the demand for loans but generally does not impact the profitability of loans since this is just a function of the spread between lending rates and funding rates (i.e. yield on asset side of the balance sheet vs. the cost of the liability side of the balance sheet), assuming of course that banks have properly hedged/matched the duration of their assets vs. liabilities. Treasury bond purchases by the Federal Reserve do not increase lending directly (the “money multiplier” is a myth) but they do increase bank profits since the resulting expansion of bank balance sheets (bonds are transformed to bank deposits and reserves at the Fed) creates another spread (with virtually no risk weighted capital requirements) which banks can collect (i.e. rate paid to depositors is less than the rate received from reserves). Mortgage backed security purchases by the Fed is potentially even more profitable for the banks as unlike Treasury purchases MBS securities contain credit risk – did the Fed pay too much for the MBS’s (money flow spent > money flow ultimately received)? Did the Fed buy the junk that the banks do not want to hold? Regardless of the effect on profitability the off-loading of MBS’s to the Fed does increase bank’s lending capacity as it reduced their capital requirements (which are based on risk weighted assets). This effect somewhat offsets new rules which are increasing bank capital requirements (to help prevent future bailouts). From a flow of funds perspective this is a good thing as increasing bank capital requires money which could otherwise flow through the economic cycle (bank capital is essentially bank savings (a stock), and like all savings represents a leakage to the economic cycle flow). The total collapse of the securitization market does negatively impact bank capital as it would require banks to own more risky assets, such as home mortgages. However, the GSE’s (e.g. Freddie and Fannie) continue to lessen this impact by insuring, or outright owning, most mortgages issued today. Lastly, we should remember that bank profits are like business profits in that they do not necessarily slow the economic cycle flow as long as they are returned to their owners (although they can still impact flows through their distributional ramifications – more on this later). Retained earnings on the other hand does slow money flows as they represent savings which add to money stocks (note that bank balance sheets are like business balance sheets in that they are linked with their owners, so bank dividends do not change net worth). So to conclude I believe that banks themselves are not a major, direct driver of the current output gap.
 Chart 11



Now that we have detailed how the actors in the economic cycle have contributed to the current output gap we can begin to identify ways in which the output gap can be eliminated. This process will be the focus of my next blog post and will involve less aggregated data which will provide a better understanding of why each sector is acting in the way which we have identified above. To preview an issue which will feature prominently in this discussion, I quote a former Federal Reserve Chairman (from 1934-1948) Marriner Eccles:

“We could do business on the basis of any dollar value as long as we have a reasonable balance between the value of all goods and services if it were not for the debt structure. The debt structure has obtained its present astronomical proportions due to an unbalanced distribution of wealth production as measured in buying power during our years of prosperity. Too much of the product of labor was diverted into capital goods, and as a result what seemed to be our prosperity was maintained on a basis of abnormal credit both at home and abroad. The time came when we seemed to reach a point of saturation in the credit structure where, generally speaking, additional credit was no longer available, with the result that debtors were forced to curtail their consumption in an effort to create a margin to apply on the reduction of debts. This naturally reduced the demand for goods of all kinds, bringing about what appeared to be overproduction, but what in reality was underconsumption measured in terms of the real world and not the money world. This naturally brought about a falling in prices and unemployment. Unemployment further decreased the consumption of goods, which further increased unemployment, thus bringing about a continuing decline in prices. Earnings began to disappear, requiring economies of all kinds – decreases in wages, salaries, and time of those employed.
…..
It is utterly impossible, as this country has demonstrated again and again, for the rich to save as much as they have been trying to save, and save anything that is worth saving. They can save idle factories and useless railroad coaches; they can save empty office buildings and closed banks; they can save paper evidences of foreign loans; but as a class they can not save anything that is worth saving, above and beyond the amount that is made profitable by the increase of consumer buying. It is for the interests of the well to do – to protect them from the results of their own folly – that we should take from them a sufficient amount of their surplus to enable consumers to consume and business to operate at a profit. This is not “soaking the rich”; it is saving the rich. Incidentally, it is the only way to assure them the serenity and security which they do not have at the present moment.”


However, my recommendations will not simply entail money flow redistribution. As I have discussed previously, the level and efficiency of real stock utilization (current standard of living) and the rate and wisdom of real stock production (future standard of living) is a function of current money flows, expectations of future money flows and the institutional structure and functioning of markets (which equate money flows with real flows via value judgments). My policy recommendations will therefore address all of these factors – simple recommendations such as more progressive taxes (which shift money flows to the less wealthy) or a workfare program (like the MMT job guarantee proposal) can potentially address the output gap issue, but by treating the symptom instead of the underlying cause.

No comments:

Post a Comment